Wednesday, February 10, 2010

Capitalism and Doctors, A Reply.

This afternoon a friend txted me over an article in the Marshall Unversity campus newspaper, The Parthenon. While reading the given article, I noticed a friend of mine wrote a column yesterday titled, For the Love of Doctors and Capitalism, which I then read. I found a comment on the column, which spurred me to respond.

Here is my reply:

Ms. White raises some very good points, particularly from where will innovation come when market incentives are replaced by government incentives. I applaud her for telling her “love story” of the only system that has pulled millions (within the last decade or so, alone) from the grinding poverty, which I am sure COLA would even renounce.

It was no other system than capitalism that broke mankind’s chains to what economists call, The Malthusian Trap, wherein with each increase in technology the population growth caused by such an increase would return the group or community back to the same standards of living, as if the technological innovation had never occurred at all.

What does this say? It says that mankind had a subsistence equilibrium from his appearance on the African savannahs to the dawn of The Industry Revolution. In other words, mankind was no better off in 1700 A.D. England than he was in 2000 B.C. Babylon or even just some clan or tribe wandering Northern Europe or the island of Japan prior to the written word, itself. Mankind had never truly improved his lot in life until Capitalism gave him the market incentives to break the bonds of subsistence. If COLA does not think man should return to the subsistence equilibrium, there are still plenty who would sent mankind back tomorrow, if they could.

Moving beyond the history lesson, the world lives off American health care innovation. The top five American hospitals conduct more clinical trails than all the hospitals in the developed world. If one cares about the poor of the world, then it stands that he or she should advocate the liberation of American health care, instead of afflicting it more so with perverse government incentives, which in return will harm the developing and developed alike.

To COLA: firstly, I do not think you are stupid, but many of the comments made in your name are excessively rude and very asinine; secondly, I am not sure where the “Rebel Flag” came in here, but nevertheless, that is another discussion; thirdly, I wish political scientists took more econ courses, then they might actually learn something about how the world works; and finally, how does one get to speak for the whole of a College on the Marshall University campus, or is it just too much trouble to be an individual these days?


I know it has been a while since my last posting, but to be honest, I have been busy. I hope to find the time to write up something soon, but no guarantees.

Tuesday, September 22, 2009

Health Care Reform and Status Quo

Several weeks back, CNBC aired, “The Meeting of the Minds: The Future of Health Care.” As advertised, this seven member panel contained “leaders, thinkers, and visionaries.”

In a short and scripted film clip, our President Obama addressed the panel, as well his fellow Americans, with a clarion call, “When we talk about the future of health care, we are talking about the future of America.”

The president continued, “There are those who argue that we cannot afford to confront the challenges of health insurance reform. But the bottom line is this: deferring the reform is nothing more than defending the status quo and the status quo is unsustainable.”

Two distinguishing remarks deserve mentioning.

Firstly, deferring one is not equivalent to defending the other;--if one so weighs the proffered reform the lesser against the current set of circumstances and affairs, no defense exists for the so-called “status quo,” only simple rationality.

For example, why would one individual acting rationally purchase a new calling plan for her cell phone wherein she will be paying substantially more for a coverage area that appears unchanged, however, now she will experience a guaranteed rise in dropped calls and additionally have more of her incoming calls sent directly to voicemail?

She simply would not, as a rational consumer. The current calling plan, no matter its shortcomings, persists as the better buy.

The task is gravely more subtle and difficult: to provide her with greater coverage with fewer dropped calls for lower the cost.

Yet, the health care reform pushed by Progressives and modern Liberals does not meet this task. These advocates forget economic data.

For example, health economist Linda Gorman notes, since “health coverage stabilized in the 1980’s,” only thirteen to sixteen percent of people have at any given time been not covered, “despite numerous expansions of government coverage programs and a massive increase in illegal immigration.”

Moreover, the only increase with government’s expansion into the health care sector has been costs. There surfaces an inverse relationship between the number of those covered and the cost of said coverage, as predicted by elementary economic theory.

Secondly, if the status quo is unsustainable, then even a “cost neutral” plan is unsustainable;--that is, if costs and the rise therewithal remain the same, then per capita costs and GDP percentage remains the same.

As Washington Post columnist, and once medical physician, Charles Krauthammer points out, “[T]he president argues that health care is killing the economy--that the costs are--and he is right in that, absolutely right.”

Krauthammer though adds, “If health care today is destroying our economy because of its costs, revenue neutrality leaves us on the same net trajectory to insolvency and ruin [the president] himself has said is going on right now.”

Only two major schemes prove to reduce costs: free markets and government rationing. The former, unlike the latter, also supports and delivers technological and procedural innovations, in so doing drives costs even further downwards.

For example, health economist John Goodman identifies lasik eye surgery--a section of health care not covered by government or even private insurers--and its rapid innovation as examples of freer markets at work.

Yet, more importantly, he mentions, compared to health care funded by government programs or paid for by insurance, the “prices on average have gone down by 30 percent.”

In sum, when President Obama says he will “not accept the status quo,” or opponents only think it is “better politics to kill this plan than improve it,” he conveniently misses that his current plan with its dubious measures is equal to, if not worse than, the status quo.

And he, therefore, overlooks the “rational consumer” in each of his fellow Americans.



This is another installment into my series on health care reform. I find the topic interesting and I hope all reading this piece does. Also, this mounts a hopeful return to writing columns for the Parthenon this term, but as a regulator, more as a fill-in on days that a weekly columnist cannot fulfill his or her deadline.

Thursday, July 23, 2009

Health Care Reform and Existing Regulations

Earlier this week, our President Obama, not knowing the truth to which he spoke, stepped forwards to assert, “Time and again, the American people have suffered because people in Washington played the politics of the moment, instead of putting the interests of the American people first.”

He continued, “That is how we ended up with premiums rising three times faster than wages; that is how we ended up with businesses choosing between shedding benefits or shutting their doors; that is how we have been burdened with runaway costs and huge gaps in coverage.”

The president undoubtedly believes more government involvement in the health care sector can “pressure” America to better-controlled costs, whilst covering an even larger segment of the American citizenry.

When he says, “[T]here are going to be some areas where we want to regulate the insurers a little more,” what is one to gather other than such?

Yet, few in Washington acknowledge--let alone accept any responsibility for--the political catastrophe wrought by decades of shortsighted regulations, instead they seek perpetually to portray this health care situation as a free market failure.

However, government-run health care, if when one views the economic literature, cannot with all its poorly channeled incentives, insulated inefficiencies, and scores of hidden costs provide patients with the quality of care and reasonable prices as well as a well-designed private sector.

With such said though, health economist Patricia Danzon wrote, “The performance of the current U.S. health care system does not provide a guide to the potential functioning of a well-designed private market system.”

She further noted, “Cost and waste in the current U.S. system are unnecessarily high because of tax and regulatory policies that impede efficient cost control by private insurers…”

The health care industry stands as one of the most heavily regulated, and thusly strangled, sectors in the American economy.

Although the multitude of these ill-starred regulations commenced rapidly in the New Deal era and developed ever-increasingly thereafter, America’s economic history has never been as laissez-faire as some, for better or worse, want to perceive.

For example, Congress insipidly mimicked the British in 1789 by funding the Marine Hospital Service by monthly taxation of American seamen.

Health economist Linda Gorman observed, “As U.S. government grew, [politicians] continued passing laws to regulate the kind of health coverage people could purchase.”

These regulations run the gamut from blocking entry into the medical profession to limiting extensively selective options for managed care plans, from artificial cost controls on insurers, hospitals, and pharmaceutical providers to numerous moralistic laws that dictate the very lives of individual Americans.

All these added regulations do not come without their own set of unpleasant economic consequences;--that is, imposed regulatory costs push up health care prices which directly lead to increased numbers of uninsured.

The economic phenomenon, known as “The Regulatory Wedge,” pilots inflation upwards due exclusively to government prescribed regulations.

With the given amount of existing regulation, some health care analysts have reported that the regulatory wedge to be larger than eight percent of total cost spent annually in this sector.

Gorman, also, remarked, “The true cost of health care was hidden from covered individuals. Vast spending increases were the result. The introduction of Medicare and Medicaid in 1965 made the situation worse.”

For example, National Bureau of Economic Research’s Amy Finkelstein discovered that Medicare itself increased real hospital expenditure by some 23 percent within the first five years of the program.

The myriad regulations, broad and minute alike, enforced by government to lessen the weight of costs below the given market equilibrium only distorts the supply-and-demand factors, whilst shifting the true cost to less seen areas.

President Obama, alongside many congressional members, lacks the economic comprehension to understand it requires more than just regulating costs, for prices are signals, or more fitting symptoms, of markets actually working, healthy or otherwise.


Several issues arose with this column. One being that the last paragraph was published without “economic,” “actually working,” as well as “otherwise” was not changed from “not.” Second being that it lacked a certain "smartassness" that I felt the other two in the series had.